Let's Connect
Follow Us
Watch Us
(+385) 1 2380 262
journal.prometfpz.unizg.hr
Promet - Traffic&Transportation journal

Accelerating Discoveries in Traffic Science

Accelerating Discoveries in Traffic Science

PUBLISHED
01.03.2024
LICENSE
Copyright (c) 2024 Ke Lu, Heng Du

Pricing Decisions for Competitive Ride-Hailing Platforms with the Combination of Inner-Group and Inter-Group Network Externalities

Authors:Ke Lu, Heng Du

Abstract

Based on two-sided market theory, this paper has studied the pricing problem of ride-hailing platforms with a combination of inter-group network externality and inner-group network externality. Two scenarios of user structure are considered. In scenario 1, both travellers and drivers are single-homing. In scenario 2, travellers are single-homing while drivers are multi-homing. Moreover, time sensitive factors and driver’s commission rate are introduced to reflect the characteristics of transport industry. Finally, the impact of network externality, time sensitivity, driver’s commission rate and entry cost on ride-hailing platform pricing, user scale and profits are analysed. The results show that inter-group network externality and inner-group network externality have a negative effect on platform prices charged to both travellers and drivers. However, when travellers are multi-homing, the price charged to travellers is positive with respect to the inter-group network externality from drivers. In the relationship between travellers’ scale and inter-group network externality, inner-group network externality is positive. Further, in both scenarios, the network externalities from the two sides affect platform profits negatively.

Keywords:ride-hailing platform, pricing decision, network externality, two-sided market

References

  1. [1] Rayle L, et al. Just a better taxi? A survey-based comparison of taxis, transit, and ridesourcing services in San Francisco. Transport Policy. 2016;45:168-178. DOI: 10.1016/j.tranpol.2015.10.004.
  2. [2] Dias FF, et al. A behavioral choice model of the use of car-sharing and ride-sourcing services. Transportation. 2017;44:1307-1323. DOI: 10.1007/s11116-017-9797-8.
  3. [3] Alemi F, et al. What drives the use of ridehailing in California? Ordered probit models of the usage frequency of Uber and Lyft. Transportation Research Part C. 2019;102:233-248. DOI: 10.1016/j.trc.2018.12.016.
  4. [4] Tang B, et al. How app-based ride-hailing services influence travel behavior: An empirical study from China. International Journal of Sustainable Transportation. 2020;14(7):554-568. DOI: 10.1080/15568318.2019.1584932.
  5. [5] Loa P, Habib KN. Examining the influence of attitudinal factors on the use of ride-hailing services in Toronto. Transportation Research Part A. 2021;146:13-28. DOI: 10.1016/j.tra.2021.02.002.
  6. [6] Hall JD, Palsson C, Price J. Is Uber a substitute or complement for public transit?. Journal of Urban Economics. 2018;108:36-50. DOI: 10.1016/j.jue.2018.09.003.
  7. [7] Shaheen S, Totte H, Stocker A. Future of mobility white paper. Institute of Transportation Studies, UC Berkeley; 2018.
  8. [8] Chen JY. Thrown under the bus and outrunning it! The logic of Didi and taxi drivers’ labour and activism in the on-demand economy. New Media & Society. 2017;1-21. DOI: 10.1177/1461444817729149.
  9. [9] Wang S, Noland RB. Variation in ride-hailing trips in Chengdu, China. Transportation Research Part D. 2021;90:102596. DOI: 10.1016/j.trd.2020.102596.
  10. [10] Brail S. World cities of ride-hailing. Urban Geography. 2022;43(1):12-33. DOI: 10.1080/02723638.2020.1775030.
  11. [11] Contreras SD, Paz A. The effects of ride-hailing companies on the taxicab industry in Las Vegas, Bevada. Transportation Research Part A. 2018;115:63-70. DOI: 10.1016/j.tra.2017.11.008.
  12. [12] Li Z, Hong Y, Zhang Z. An empirical analysis of on-demand ride sharing and traffic congestion. Proceedings of the 50th Hawaii International Conference on System Science, Hawaii, USA. 2017. p. 4-13.
  13. [13] Wirtz J, Tang C. Uber: Competing as market leader in the US versus being a distant second in China. Services Marketing: People Technology Strategy. 2016;626-632. DOI: 10.1142/9781944659028_0019.
  14. [14] Kulińska E, Kulińska K. Development of ride-sourcing services and sustainable city logistics. Transportation Research Procedia. 2019;39:252-259. DOI: 10.1016/j.trpro.2019.06.027.
  15. [15] Katz ML, Shapiro C. Network externalities, competition, and compatibility. The American Economic Review. 1985;75(3):424-440.
  16. [16] Katz ML, Shapiro C. Product introduction with network externalities. The Journal of Industrial Economics. 1992;40(1):55-83.
  17. [17] Lee D, Choi K. The efficiency of competing vertical chains with network externalities. Economics Letters. 2018;168:1-5. DOI: 10.1016/j.econlet.2018.03.019.
  18. [18] Zha L, Yin Y, Yang H. Economic analysis of ride-sourcing markets. Transportation Research Part C. 2016;71:249-266. DOI: 10.1016/j.trc.2016.07.010.
  19. [19] Zha L, Yin Y, Du Y. Surge pricing and labor supply in the ride-sourcing market. Transportation Research Part B. 2018;117:708-722. DOI: 10.1016/j.trb.2017.09.010.
  20. [20] Sun L, et al. Optimal pricing for ride-sourcing platforms. European Journal of Operational Research. 2019;278:783-795. DOI: 10.1016/j.ejor.2019.04.044.
  21. [21] Wu T, et al. Spatial differentiation and network externality in pricing mechanism of online car hailing platform. International Journal of Production Economics. 2020;219:275-283. DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2019.05.007.
  22. [22] Yan C, et al. Dynamic pricing and matching in ride-hailing platforms. Naval Research Logistics. 2020;67:705-724. DOI: 10.1002/nav.218.
  23. [23] Hu B, Hu M, Zhu H. Surge pricing and two-sided temporal responses in ride hailing. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management. 2021;24(1):91-109. DOI: 10.1287/msom.2020.0960.
  24. [24] Didi. Annual business and social responsibility report. 2022.
  25. https://s28.q4cdn.com/896456191/files/doc_financials/2022/ar/2022-Annual-Business-and-Social-Responsibility-Report.pdf [Accessed 23th Aug. 2023].
  26. [25] Henao A, Marshall WE. An analysis of the individual economics of ride-hailing drivers. Transportation Research Part A. 2019;130:440-451. DOI: 10.1016/j.tra.2019.09.056.
  27. [26] Meskar M, Aslani S, Modarres M. Spatio-temporal pricing algorithm for ride-hailing platforms where drivers can decline ride requests. Transportation Research Part C. 2023;153:104200. DOI: 10.1016/j.trc.2023.104200.
  28. [27] Garg N, Nazerzadeh H. Driver surge pricing. Management Science. 2021;68(5):3219-3235. DOI: 10.1287/mnsc.2021.4058.
  29. [28] Rochet JC, Tirole J. Platform competition in two-sided markets. Journal of the European Economic Association. 2003;1(4):990-1029. DOI: 10.1162/154247603322493212.
  30. [29] Rochet JC, Tirole J. Two-sided markets: A progress report. RAND Journal of Economics. 2006;37(3):645-667. DOI: 10.1111/J.1756-2171.2006.tb00036.x.
  31. [30] Armstrong M. Competition in two-sided markets. RAND Journal of Economics. 2006;37(3):668-691. DOI: 10.1111/j.1756-2171.2006.tb00037.x.
  32. [31] Jang DC, Kim B, Lee SY. A two-sided market platform analysis for the electric vehicle adoption: Firm strategies and policy design. Transportation Research Part D. 2018;62:646-658. DOI: 10.1016/j.trd.2018.02.002.
  33. [32] Belleflamme P, Peitz M. Managing competition on a two-sided platform. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy. 2019;28(1):5-22. DOI: 10.1111/jems.12311.
  34. [33] Li J, Zhang Y. The side with larger network externality should be targeted aggressively? Monopoly pricing, reference price and two-sided markets. Electronic Commerce Research and Applications. 2020;43:100995. DOI: 10.1016/j.elerap.2020.100995.
  35. [34] Tang F, Chi K. Research on pricing strategy of online group buying in two-sided network [双边网络环境下的网络团购定价策略研究]. Chinese Journal of Management Science. 2013;21(3):185-192. DOI: 10.16381/j.cnki.issn1003-207x.2013.03.020.
  36. [35] Hotelling H. Stability in competition. The Economic Journal. 1929;39(153):41-57. DOI: 10.2307/2224214.
  37. [36] Adler N, Brudner A, Proost S. A review of transport market modeling using game-theoretic principles. European Journal of Operational Research. 2021;291:808-829. DOI: 10.1016/j.ejor.2020.11.020.
  38. [37] Li S, Liu Y, Bandyopadhyay S. Network effects in online two-sided market platforms: A research note. Decision Support Systems. 2010;49:245-249. DOI: 10.1016/j.dss.2010.02.004.
  39. [38] Xu W, Lin G, Zhu X. Bundling strategies for ride-hailing platforms based on price and service level. Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research. 2022;17(2):851-874. DOI: 10.3390/jtaer17020044.
  40. [39] Wei X, et al. Optimal business model for the monopolistic ride-hailing platform: Pooling, premier, or hybrid?. Knowledge-Based Systems. 2020;204:106093. DOI: 10.1016/j.knosys.2020.106093.
  41. [40] Wang M, Mu L. Spatial disparities of Uber accessibility: An exploratory analysis in Atlanta, USA. Computers, Environment and Urban Systems. 2018;67:169-175. DOI: 10.1016/j.compenvurbsys.2017.09.003.
  42. [41] Chen X, et al. Dynamic optimization strategies for on-demand ride services platform: Surge pricing, commission rate, and incentives. Transportation Research Part B. 2020;138:23-45. DOI: 10.1016/j.trb.2020.05.005.
Show more


Accelerating Discoveries in Traffic Science |
2024 © Promet - Traffic&Transportation journal